




版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
RecyclinginaGlobalizedEconomy
EugénieJoltreauandLuisSarmiento
WorkingPaper25-19
July2025
PAGE
1
RecyclinginaGlobalizedEconomy?
EugénieJoltreau1,2,* LuisSarmiento1,2,3
Developingacirculareconomythroughwasterecyclinghasemergedasaparadigmforconservingnonrenewableresources.Butwhatdoesimplementingacirculareconomymeaninthecontextofglobalizedeconomies?Wastegeneratedbyconsumption,in-cludingimports,oftenmisalignswithnationalproductionandexportmaterialneeds.Thismaterialmismatch,termed"materialimbalances,"alongwithvariationsinwastedisutility,costs,andaccesstovirginresourcesacrosscountries,shapeslocalandin-ternationaltradestrategiesrelatedtowaste.Thispaperoffersanewperspectiveonrecyclingpolicies,emphasizinginternationaltradeandnationalmaterialimbal-ances.Wetheoreticallycharacterizetheexistenceofawastemarketforrecyclinganddemonstratethatlocalrecyclingincentivepoliciescandriveorreducewasteexportsdependingontheirdesign.Additionally,weshowboththeoreticallyandempiricallythatrelativematerialimbalancesbetweencountriesareakeydeterminantofwastetradeforrecycling.
JELcodes:Q53;H23;L33;L51
Keywords:CircularEconomy,InternationalTradeofWaste,EnvironmentalPolicy
Acknowledgements:E.J.acknowledgesfundingbytheEuropeanUnionundertheHorizonEuroperesearchandinnovationprogram,projectCircEUlar(GANo.101056810).
1RFF-CMCCEuropeanInstituteonEconomicsandtheEnvironment,Milan,Italy.
2CentroEuro-MediterraneoSuiCambiamentiClimatici,Lecce,Italy.
3BancodeMéxico,Merida,Mexico.
*Correspondingauthor.E-mail:
eugenie.joltreau@cmcc.it
?
WethankDominikWiedenhoferandJanStreeckforsharingthematerialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO)modeldatawithus.WethankWeiGuoandRouhanSongfortheirhelpwiththereportsoftheChineseMinistryofCommerce.WethanktheparticipantsofEEA-ESEM2021fortheirhelpfulcommentsandparticipantsfromthe2022seminarofUniversitéParisDauphine,PSL,andCEE-M(INRAE).
Wearesolelyresponsibleforanyerrorsinthemanuscriptandreportnoconflictsofinterest.
PAGE
2
Introduction
Thecirculareconomyisoftendiscussedfromlocaltonationallevels(Korhonen,HonkasaloandSepp?l?,2018);however,materialflowsexistwithintheframeworkofinternationaltrade.Globaltradecancreatemismatchesbetweenwastegenerationandthelocationswherematerialsareneededforproduction.Forinstance,somecountriesgenerateexcesswastematerialsthatcouldprovideinputsforindustriesinothernations.
Atthesametime,secondarymaterialsfromconsumption(wasteandrecycledmaterials)aretradedglobally.Asizeableglobalwastemarketexists—nearlyUSD100billionand218milliontons(2016value;OECD,2018).Ascountriesandregionsoftenimplementpolicieswithoutconsideringtheinternationalnatureofmaterialflows,weaimtounderstandthedeterminantsoftheglobalwastemarketforrecyclinganditsrelationtonationalrecyclingpoliciesandupstreamglobalization.
Wedeveloptheconceptofmaterialimbalance,definedasthemismatchbetweenmaterialsneededforproductionandwastegeneratedfromconsumption.Wethenformulateatheoreticalmodeltocharacterizetheinternationalmarketforpostconsumptionwaste,emphasizingitsinteractionwithnationalrecyclingpoliciesandmaterialimbalances.Finally,weempiricallytestthelinkbetweencountry-pairmaterialimbalancesandwastetrade.
Theliteratureonwastetradehasprimarilyfocusedonthewastehavenhypothesisandex-portsfordisposal(Copeland,1991;Baggs,2009;Kellenberg,2010,2012;EggerandKeuschnigg,2024),illegaltradeflows(Copeland,1991;Bernard,2015;Sun,2019)andwastetradeforreuse(YokooandKinnaman,2013;Bernard,2015);weprovidethefirstcharacterizationofinterna-tionalwastetradeforrecycling.Understandingthisiscrucialbecausereusemeetsconsumptionneeds,whereasrecyclablewasteservesasaproductioninput.Thisdistinctionimpliesdifferentdynamicswithinthevaluechain.Wefurthercontributetotheliteraturebyanalyzingtheeffectsofnationalrecyclingpoliciesinthecontextofglobalizedmaterialflows,suchasDussauxandGlachant(2019),García-BarragánandZelity(2019)andEggerandKeuschnigg(2024).1Toourknowledge,thisisthefirstarticleintheinternationaltradeandcirculareconomyliteraturetoutilizetheconceptofmaterialimbalancetocharacterizeinternationalmarketsforwasteandrecycledmaterials.
Webeginbymotivatingthetheoreticalmodelwithaseriesofstylizedfactsaboutinternationaltradeinrecyclablematerials,includingplastics,glass,steelandiron,aluminum,andpaper.
1AppendixA.1presentsacompletediscussionofthewastetradeliterature.
PAGE
3
First,wedocumentthemagnitude,composition,anddirectionofglobaltradeflowsinwasteusingcustomdata.Weconcludethatthevolumeoftradeinrecyclablewasteissignificant,amountingto52megatonnes(Mt)in2016.Notably,asignificantshareofthis—exceeding50Mt—hasoriginatedfromhigh-incomecountriesandbeenexportedworldwidesincethe2000s.Next,weexaminematerialimbalances(materialneedsformanufacturingminuswastegeneratedbyconsumption).Wefindthathigh-incomecountrieshaveaproduction-dominatedmaterialimbalance(exceptforpaper),butonethattendstodecrease(thevolumeofwasteincreasesfasterthanproductiveneeds).Incontrast,therestoftheworldexperiencesasignificantaccelerationinmaterialneedscomparedtowasteproduction.Finally,wedemonstratethatrecyclingpoliciesandthewastemarketinteract.WeestimatetheelasticitybetweenwasteexportsandnationalrecyclingratesinEurope,rangingfroma20percentagepointincreaseintherecyclingratefora1percentincreaseinwasteexportsforislandnations,likeMaltaandCyprus,to5–10percentagepointsforlargereconomies.
Ourtheoreticalmodelanalyzescountries’trade,disposal,andrecyclingdecisionsbasedontheirmaterialimbalances,nationaleconomicconditions,andglobalmarketpriceswithinastaticframework.ItincorporatesresourceendowmentsinthespiritoftheHeckscher-Ohlinframework,withthekeydistinctionthatwasteendowmentsaredeterminedbyconsumptionpatterns,whicharethemselvesinfluencedbyexogenousinternationalflowsoffinalgoods.Unlikeaconventionalmarketforgoodsorpollution,thismodelfeaturesanambivalentpricethatcanfluctuatebetweenpositiveandnegativevalues.2Itmakesseveralassumptions,includingashortageofprimarymaterials,asdocumentedbyYoshidaetal.(2005)forChina.Itexcludestradeinvirginresourcestofocussolelyonthedownstreamsector.Weassumethatallwasteisrecyclableatagivencost.
Thefirstequilibriumconsidersacompetitiveextractionindustrywithrespecttorecycling.Wedefineawasteexporterprofilecharacterizedbylowcollectioncosts,highdisposalandrecyclingcosts,andawaste-dominatedmaterialimbalance,contrastingwiththewasteimporterprofile.Wefindthatawastemarketemergesbetweentwocountrieswhenmutuallybeneficialtradeop-portunitiesarisefromasymmetriesinmaterialimbalances,lowtransportcosts,andvariationsinwastecollection,recycling,anddisposalcosts.ThisinsighthelpsusunderstandthesignificantwastetradebetweenEuropeandAsia.Inthisequilibrium,ourtheoreticalmodeldemonstratesthattradedoesnotaffectglobalrecycling;wasteexportsmerelyshifttotheimportingcoun-try,wherethewasteisrecycled,substitutingfornationalwastecollectionandrecycling.ThisalignswithChina’sstatementsthatbanningwasteimportsaimedtostimulatedomesticrecycling
2Themodelconsidersillegaltradeasthemodel’sboundary;whenthepricebecomestoonegative,themarketcanbecomeadumpingmarket.
PAGE
4
(ISWA,2018)andwithdatafromtheChineseMinistryofCommerceindicatinganincreaseindomesticrecyclingafterbanningimports(AppendixA.10).Thisisarelevantfindingfortheliteratureandpublicdebates,whichfocusedonthewastehavenhypothesisandtradeinwastefordisposal(Copeland,1991;Kellenberg,2012)orconsideredtradeinwasteasawaytoincreaseglobalrecyclingwhileminimizingeconomiccosts(OECD,2018).Inaddition,themodelshowsthatpoliciesbasedoneconomicincentivesinthewaste-exportingcountrytendtofavorexportsoverlocalrecyclinguptoacertainthreshold—untilthenetenvironmentalbenefitsofrecyclingexceedtheresidualneedformaterials.Inthisequilibrium,incorporationratesaremoreefficientthanrecyclingtargetsinincreasinglocalrecyclingforawasteexporterprofile.
Thesecondequilibriumemergeswhenrecyclingbecomesmoresociallycompetitiveduetohigherdisposalcostsandlowerrecyclingcosts.Thisshiftreflectsthestrengtheningofrecyclingpoliciesinthewaste-exportingcountry.Thosepoliciesenhancelocalrecycling,whichsubstitutesforvirginresources.Theimpactonwasteexportsismorenuanced:althoughtherecyclingsubsidyreducesexports,thedisposaltaxnolongerhasanyinfluence.Thecollectionsubsidystimulatesexportsbydrivingdownwasteprices.However,iftheglobalwastepricedropstoosharply,itcanincentivizeillegaltradefordisposal.
Accordingtothefirstequilibriumandassumingtheequalizationofothervariables,3atrademarketforwasterecyclingemergeswhencountrieshavedifferentrelativematerialimbalances.Intheempiricalsection,wetestthismodelpredictionbyexamininghowmaterialimbalancesbetweentwocountriesaffectwastetradewithinagravitymodelframework.UsingaPoissonpseudo-maximumlikelihoodestimator(PPMLE),wefindanelasticityof0.8betweenrelativematerialimbalanceandwastetradeforrecyclablematerials.Thisresultremainssignificantacrossdifferentspecifications,estimators,andmaterials,confirmingourtheoreticalcontribution.
Ourresultshaveseveralpolicyimplications.Thetheoreticalmodelindicatesthatwasteimporterprofilesareeconomieswithhighmaterialneeds,lowerdisposalandrecyclingcosts,andunderde-velopedcollectionandsortingsystems.Thisprofilematchesdevelopingeconomies,asconfirmedbythestylizedfacts,raisingbothenvironmentalandethicalconcerns.Developedcountriesmaythusstrengthenlocalrecyclingsystemstodecreasewasteexportsandcombatresourcescarcity.However,themodelrevealsthatpoorlydesignedrecyclingpoliciesmayunintentionallyencour-agewasteexportswithoutimprovingdomesticrecycling.Boththetheoreticalandempiricalmodelsrecognizematerialimbalancesasakeyfactorinfluencingwastetrade.Toaddressthisis-sue,exportingcountriescanadoptstrategiessuchasincreasinglocalmaterialdemand—through
3collection,disposalandrecyclingcosts,andvirginresourceavailability
PAGE
5
reindustrialization,forexample—andreducingwastebypromotingconsumptionsufficiencyandextendingproductlifecycles.However,anypolicyaimedatboostingmaterialdemandmustalignwithglobalsustainabilitygoals,acknowledgingtheneedtoreduceoverallresourceusetorespectplanetaryboundaries(Rockstr?metal.,2009).
Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows:Section2presentsstylizedfactsonthetradeinrecyclablewaste,Section3displaysthetheoreticalmodel,andSection4empiricallytestsourtheory.Section5concludes.
StylizedFacts
AMajorTradeinRecyclableWaste
Theinternationaltradeinwasteissubstantial.In2016,itaccountedfor0.6percentofglobaltradevalue(OECD,2018).Itmainlyconsistedofmetal,paper,andplasticwaste(OECD,2018).Whenfocusingtherecyclablewastematerialsconsideredinthispaper,4thisfigureisabout0.53percentofthetotalvalueofinternationaltrade,comparabletotheannualtradeincoal,medicalinstruments,orsemiconductorsforthatyear(OrganizationforEconomicComplexity,2016).
Figure1presentstheevolutionofwastevolumesin(a)andthebalanceofwastetradeacrossincomegroupsin(b).WeconstructthisfigureusingdatafromtheBACIdatabasefromtheCentred’EtudesProspectivesetd’InformationsInternationales.Wecategorizecountriesintohigh-incomeandrestoftheworldaccordingtotheWorldBankclassification.Wefocusonthefivemainrecyclablewasteproducts:plastics,paper,aluminum,glass,andsteel/iron.5
Thevolumeofwastetradegrewsteadilyfromthebeginningofthecenturyuntilthe2008financialcrisis,increasingfrom84to181Mt.Despitethemarkeddecreasein2009,from2010,tradevolumeshaveremainedstableat170–200Mtperyear.Themostimportantrecyclablematerialbyvolumetradedissteel/iron,followedbypaper,plastic,aluminum,andglass.Panel
b)depictsthebalanceofwastetradebetweenhigh-incomecountriesandtherestoftheworld.Thistimeseriesconfirmsresearchindicatingagrowingsupplyofrecyclablewastetradefromhigh-tolower-incomeeconomiesstartinginthe2000s(CEPII,2012).In2022,high-incomecountrieshadrecyclablewastetradesurplusesofupto72Mt.
Themarketforrecyclablewasteishighlyconcentrated.Thetop10countriesaccountfor67
4Weconsiderfivewastematerials:plastics,paper,aluminum,glass,andsteel/iron,aligningwithEuropeanUnionpackagingrecyclingrequirements(Directive2018/852).
5WepresentthedataworkandotherstatisticsinAppendixA.3.
PAGE
6
Figure1:RecyclableWasteVolumeandValues
Notes:Self-constructeddatawithfiguresfromtheBasepourl’AnalyseduCommerceInternational.HScodesareinAppendixA.3.
percentofglobalwasteexports.Theonlynon-high-incomecountryinthisgroupisRussia.ThemainexportersaretheUnitedStates,Germany,Japan,andGreatBritain,withglobalsharesof19,10,7,and7percent,respectively.Chinaisthelargestimporter,accountingfor13.8percentofallimportsbetween2001and2022,followedbyGermany,Turkey,India,andKorea.
CountriesExhibitingMaterialImbalances
Globalizationandspecializationcancreatematerialimbalancesbecausedifferentspecializationsrequirevaryingresourceamounts.Forinstance,aserviceeconomytypicallyusesfewermaterialsforproductioncomparedtoamanufacturing-focusedeconomy.Moreover,aserviceeconomythatconsumeslargequantitiesofmanufacturedgoodsmaygeneratemorewastefromconsumptionthanitproduces.Incontrast,aneconomycenteredonresource-intensiveproductioncanproducelesswastethanitconsumes.Otherfactorscontributetothesediscrepancies,suchasproductlife-span,whichaffectswasteoutput,andlevelsofeconomicgrowthandurbanization,whichinfluenceproductionneeds.
Todocumentandprovideevidenceofmaterialimbalances,weusedatafromthematerialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO2)modelfromWiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Grammer,Baumgart,Plank,Helbig,Pauliuk,HaberlandKrausmann(2024);Wiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Gram-mer,BaumgartandPlank(2024).Itisanadvanced,dynamic,inflow-drivenmodelthatprovidesacomprehensiveframeworkforanalyzingmaterialstocksandflowsacrossvarioussectors.6
6Ittracksmaterialsfromextractionthroughprocessing,trade,andproductuse,ultimatelyleadingtorecycling
PAGE
7
Figure2showsthedifferencebetweenthematerialsembodiedintheproductionofdomesticmanufacturedgoods(includingexports)andthoseintheapparentconsumptionofmanufacturedgoods(includingimports).7Exceptforglass,high-incomecountriesexhibitadifferentialfavoringconsumptioninmostrecentyears.Incontrast,therestoftheworldshowsanincreasingsurplusrelatedtoproductiveneeds.Thisdiscrepancysuggestsagrowingdemandformaterialsintheproductionofmanufacturedgoodsindevelopingnations,especiallyforexports.
Figure2:MaterialImbalancefromFinalProductionandConsumption
Notes:Thisfigurepresentsthetimeseriesofmaterialimbalanceembeddedinthedifferencesbetweenproductiveneedsandconsumption.Weconstructthedatasetfromtheeconomy-wide,dynamic,inflow-drivenmodelofmaterialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO2)developedbyWiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Grammer,Baumgart,Plank,Helbig,Pauliuk,HaberlandKrausmann(2024).Toconstructthetimeseries,weuseMISO2-reporteddataonmaterialsembodiedinfinalproduction(F78)minusmaterialembodiedinlocalconsumption(F89).Thatis,materialimbalancefromproductionandconsumptionisF78–F89andshowsthemismatchbetweenacountry’scontemporarymaterialneedsforitsproductionprocessesandthematerialsembeddedinconsumption.Oncewecalculatethisvalueforeachcountry,weaggregatebycountrygroupbysummingoverallthecountriesinthatgroupandyear.
However,ourmaterialimbalanceconceptfocusesonavailablewasteratherthanmaterialem-bodiedinconsumption(i.e.,itintegratesproductlife-spans).Forinstance,arapidlyurbanizingeconomymayexhibithighmaterialconsumption,butthesematerialscanremaininuseforanextendedperiod.Incontrast,amatureeconomythatconsumesfewerdurablegoodsgenerateswastemorequickly.Figure3illustratesthedifferencebetweenmaterialsembodiedinthepro-ductionofmanufacturedgoodsandthewastegeneratedfromconsumption(afteruseintheeconomy).Exceptforpaper,thematerialimbalanceofhigh-incomecountriesispositiveand
orwaste.MISO2provideshigh-resolutiondatafor177countriesfrom1900to2016,withaspin-upperiodstartingin1820.AnotablefeatureofMISO2isitsconsistencywitheconomy-widematerialflowaccounting(ew-MFA),whichensuresasystematicmassbalancethroughouttheentirematerialcycle.
7F_7_8andF_8_9intheMISO2variabledefinition.
PAGE
8
morestable.Nevertheless,itmostlyshowsaslightdownwardtrend(afasterincreaseinwasteproductionthanproductiveneeds;itismorestableforglass).Thesituationfortherestoftheworldisentirelyopposite,withmaterialrequirementsrisingsharplyrelativetowasteproduced.
Figure3:MaterialImbalanceConsideringProducts’Life-Span
Notes:Thisfigurepresentsthetimeseriesofmaterialimbalanceembeddedinthedifferencesbetweenproductiveneedsandwastegenerationfromconsumption.Weconstructthedatasetfromtheeconomy-wide,dynamic,inflow-drivenmodelofmaterialinputs,stocks,andoutputs(MISO2)developedbyWiedenhofer,Streeck,Wieland,Grammer,Baumgart,Plank,Helbig,Pauliuk,HaberlandKrausmann(2024).Toconstructthetimeseries,weuseMISO2-reporteddataonfinalmaterialproductionneeds(F78)minusend-of-lifewasteflows(F1011).Thatis,materialimbalancefromproductionandwastegenerationisF78–F1011andshowsthemismatchbetweenacountry’scontemporarymaterialneedsforitsproductionprocessesandtheavailablewastematerialsafterconsumption.Oncewecalculatethisvalueforeachcountry,weaggregatebycountrygroupbysummingoverallthecountriesinthatgroupandyear.
TheWasteMarketInteractingwithDomesticRecyclingPolicies
Inadditiontomaterialimbalanceandmarketforces,policiescanalsosignificantlyinfluencethewastemarket.TheEuropeanUnionexemplifiesthisphenomenon.Itsetspackagingrecyclingquotasformemberstates,whichtheycanfulfillthroughwasteexportforrecycling.8
WedemonstratethescaleofrecyclingexportsinrelationtotherecyclingperformanceofEuro-peancountries.Ouraimisnottodemonstrateacausallink,asitexistsbylaw.Ourobjectiveistoelucidatethephenomenon’sscaleandunderscoreitspolicyrelevance.WeusethepackagingrecyclingdataproducedbyEUROSTAT9andBACIforwasteexports.
8SeeDirective2018/852,whichamendedDirective1994/62/EC.Thesetargetsarealsodefinedatthepackagingmateriallevel:forinstance,50percentforplasticandaluminum,75percentforpaperandcardboard,and70percentforferrousmetals(Directive2018/852).
9Thisdatasetonlycoverspackagingwaste.Itexcludesotherwasteproductsofthesamematerials,suchas
homeappliances,clothing,andtools.
9
Since2018,membercountriesmustreporttheshareofrecyclingthatoccursoutsidetheEuropeanUnion.InTable1,wepresenttheaveragerecyclingsharesinthehomecountry,withintheEuropeanUnion,andoutsidetheEuropeanUnionfrom2018to2021.Onaverage,10–13percentoccursoutsidetheEuropeanUnion.
Table1:Avg.WasteGenerationandRecyclingSharesintheEuropeanUnion(2018–2021)
Generation(MT)
Share
Share
Share
Share
2018
3.03
61.98
59.34
32.04
13.19
2019
2.72
60.83
56.89
30.92
13.36
2020
3.06
61.40
58.26
27.46
13.83
2021
3.25
62.21
59.95
29.74
10.30
Avg.Waste
Recycling
LocalRecycling
EuropeanUnionRecycling
ForeignRecycling
Notes:ThistablepresentstheaverageannualvaluesacrossallEuropeanUnioncountriesforfivevariables:averagewastegenerationinmegatonnes,averagerecyclingrate,localrecyclingshare(thepercentageoftotalrecyclinghappeningdomestically),EuropeanUnionrecyclingshare(thepercentageoftotalrecyclingthatoccursinothermemberstates),andforeignrecyclingshare(thepercentageoftotalrecyclinghappeningincountriesoutsidetheEuropeanUnion).
However,dependingonthematerial,thissharewaslikelymuchhigherbeforetheChineseban.AccordingtoEuropeanParliament(2018),theEuropeanUnionusedtoexportapproximatelyhalfofitsplasticsdestinedforrecycling.Thiscouldhaveaccountedforupto50percentofEuropeancountries’plasticrecyclingrates,raisingconcernsabouttheirdependenceonforeignmarketsforwastemanagement.
Figure4presentstwosimpleexercisestoillustratetherelationshipbetweenrecyclingratesandwasteexportsamongEuropeanUnionmemberstates.Theleftpanelshowsascatterplotofrecyclingratesandtotalwasteexportsfrom2000to2021forthe15largesteconomiesintheEuropeanUnion,whichmandatesaminimumrecyclingrateof65percentforallpackagingwasteby2025.Thefigureincludesalinearfitforeachcountryinalevel-logspecification.Fourteenofthe15largesteconomiesshowapositiverelationshipbetweentheirrecyclingratesandwasteexports.10Atthetopright,weestimatetheelasticitybetweenthesetwofactorsusingasimplelevel-logmodelforeachcountry.11Thecoefficientsrangefrom26pp(Malta)to-6pp(Romania).Ofthe27countriesinthesample,23(85percent)showapositiveestimate,andonly4haveanegativecoefficient.Amongthe23countrieswithapositiveestimate,onlytwoarenotstatisticallydifferentfromzeroatthe10percentlevel,andnoneofthefourwithnegativecoefficientsisstatisticallysignificant.FourofthefivelargesteconomiesintheEuropeanUnion(France,Italy,Spain,andtheNetherlands)showapositiveandsignificantpointestimate.Inthebottomrightcorner,wepresenttheactualshareofrecyclingoutsidetheEuropeanUnionbetween2018and2022forcomparison.12Theratesareparticularlyhighforislandeconomies,
10TheonlyexceptionisGermany.Apossiblehypothesistotestisthatvariationsinlocalrecyclingorintra-
Europeanexportsbetterexplaintheincreaseinitsrecyclingrate.
11TheestimatedequationisRct=log(Wct)+?ct.Rctistherecyclingrateforcountrycattimet,andWctisthetotalvolumeofwasteexportsoutsidetheEuropeanUnion.
12Thisinformationisunavailableforyearsbefore2018.However,themarketunderwentsignificantchangesafter
PAGE
10
whichalignwiththeirelasticities.
Figure4:EuropeanUnionRecyclingRatesandWasteExports
Notes:ThisfigurepresentstherelationshipbetweenEuropeanUnionrecyclingratesandwasteexports.PanelapresentsascatterplotoftherecyclingrateandthetotalwasteexportsoutsidetheEuropeanUnionbetween2000and2022forthe15largestEuropeanUnioneconomies.Foreachcountry,weindependentlymakealinearfitacrossallyearlyobservations.Panelbpresentsthepointestimatesofasimpleordinaryleastsquareslevel-logmodeloftherecyclingrateasafunctionofwasteexports.WeestimatethemodelindependentlyforeachEuropeanUnioncountryandplotpointestimatesand95percentconfidenceintervals.
TheTheoreticalModel
AutarkyinResources
Westartbyconsideringaneconomyinresourceautarkythatprohibitstradeinvirginresourcesandsecondarymaterialsor,alternatively,auniformglobaleconomy.
ThecountryhasasingleagentthatproducesgoodsfromauniquematerialwithweightQˉ,whosequantityisdeterminedexogenouslybyconsumerdemand.Inthepreviousperiod,theagentconsumedaquantityofgoodsC,whichisnowavailableasrecyclablewasteCw.Nonrecycledwasteisdisposedofwithdisutilityωandcostlyfortheuniqueagentofthecountry.Wedonotconsiderwastefromthepreviousperiodatdumpsitesforrecyclinginthecurrentperiod.ToproduceQˉ,theagentmustchoosebetweenusingthevirginnationalresourceRfromtheresourcereservoir(Rˉ)orrecyclingashareτofthenewlyavailablenationalwasteCw.
Intherecyclingvaluechain(collection,sorting,recycling),weassumethatcostconvexityexistsonlyinthecollectionandsortingprocesses,whichwemodelasthesamestep.Weconsider
Chinaimposedstrictrestrictionsonwasteimportsin2017.
PAGE
11
auniformdistributionofmaterialwastein[0,1],where0denotesthelocationoftherecyclingindustryandfirm,asinFleckingerandJoltreau(2020).Theagentstartsbycollectingthemostaccessiblewaste.Wastecollectionincursaunitcostγ.Thus,thecollectioncostscanbeexpressedasfollows:
r
τ
γ xdx=
0
γτ2
2
(1)
Costconvexityarisesbecausethelastcollectedwasteisoftenthemostexpensive,suchasfromremoteareasorhouseholdsthatresistsorting.13Anotherinterpretationisthatwastequalityvariesfrom0(pure)to1(impure);γrepresentsthesortingpremiumassociatedwithimpurity.Theunitcostofrecyclingthecollectedwasteisα,whichincludesrecyclingstandardsandnorms.
Weassumethatvirginresources(R)concentrateatpoint0andthatextractionoccursataconstantunitcostr.Extractioncostsincreaseovertime(Hotelling,1931),andcollectioncostsoccurperiodically.Inthismodel,weadoptastaticperspective.Hence,foragivenyear,wemodelextractioncostsasaconstantunitcost,allowingconvexityonlyinco
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 廉潔過(guò)節(jié)試題及答案
- 三基訓(xùn)練試題及答案
- 初級(jí)中醫(yī)考試題及答案
- 天價(jià)彩禮面試題及答案
- 醫(yī)師招考試題及答案
- 產(chǎn)品知識(shí)試題及答案
- 鐵路實(shí)訓(xùn)考試試題及答案
- 語(yǔ)文小升初考試題及答案
- 鋼琴七級(jí)試題及答案
- 基層自治面試題及答案
- 客艙乘務(wù)員疲勞問(wèn)題分析及對(duì)策研究-以A航空公司為例
- 城管協(xié)管員筆試考題試題(含答案)大全五篇
- 駕照體檢表完整版本
- 實(shí)驗(yàn)教學(xué)創(chuàng)新設(shè)計(jì)
- ?;钒踩芾砼嘤?xùn)培訓(xùn)教材
- 《血液儲(chǔ)存要求》(WS 399-2012)試題及答案
- 原發(fā)性骨質(zhì)疏松癥診療指南(2022)解讀
- 新概念英語(yǔ)“第一冊(cè)”單詞對(duì)照表
- 新生兒早期基本保健(EENC)-新生兒早期基本保健(EENC)概述(兒童保健課件)
- 加油站高處墜落事故現(xiàn)場(chǎng)處置方案
- 男性性功能障礙專家講座
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論